Recycling Revenue from a Carbon Tax

A national tax on carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions is a cost-effective and efficient tool to achieve environmentally beneficial emissions reductions that will generate billions of dollars per year in revenue for the US government. These carbon revenues can serve a range of purposes. They can pay for energy efficiency investments; they can finance cuts in current distortionary taxes, payments to negatively affected stakeholders, or dividend checks to all households; or they can help reduce the federal deficit.

We examine the impacts of alternative revenue recycling options in our recent paper, in which we compare lump-sum rebates (dividend checks), cuts in personal and/or corporate income taxes, and a tradable exemption option for carbon-intensive industries. Using the Goulder-Hafstead E3 model of the US economy, which offers a detailed representation of domestic energy supply and demand alongside a detailed tax system, we show that using carbon tax revenue to finance marginal tax rate cuts can significantly lower the cost of the carbon tax relative to lump-sum rebates.

Overall, personal income tax cuts reduce GDP costs by 42 percent relative to lump-sum rebates while corporate income tax cuts offer a 58 percent cost reduction relative to lump-sum rebates. Tradable exemptions are able to reduce a carbon tax’s negative impact on profits for the carbon-intensive industries that receive the exemptions; however, exemptions reduce the revenue that can be used to finance tax cuts and therefore they are a less cost-effective method than using all of the carbon revenue to reduce distortionary taxes.

Carbon-intensive industries such as coal mining, coal-fired electricity generation, and petroleum refining potentially suffer significant profit losses when revenues are recycled through personal income tax cuts. The losses to carbon-intensive industries are considerably smaller when the revenues are devoted to corporate income tax cuts. When tradable exemptions are offered to these industries, however, their losses are reduced even further; in fact, a well-designed allocation of exemptions could completely eliminate profit losses in the most vulnerable industries.

We estimate that a carbon tax that starts at $10 per ton and increases by 5 percent each year has the potential to generate $690 billion in gross revenue in the first 10 years of the policy. The net revenue—the amount that can be devoted to cuts in distortionary taxes—will be considerably lower because of declines in the tax revenue generated by other taxes and increases in nominal government spending induced by increases in the price level. Despite these offsets, a carbon tax generates significant revenue that can be used to contribute to meaningful general tax reform while reducing harmful CO2 emissions.

 

 

About Lawrence H. Goulder

Lawrence H. Goulder is the Shuzo Nishihara Professor in Environmental and Resource Economics at Stanford University and director of the Stanford Center for Environmental and Energy Policy Analysis. He is also the Kennedy-Grossman Fellow in Human Biology at Stanford; a senior fellow at Stanford's Institute for Economic Policy Research; a research associate at the National Bureau of Economic Research; and a university fellow at Resources for the Future.

About Marc Hafstead

Marc Hafstead is a Fellow at Resources for the Future. His research spans environmental and macroeconomics, with an emphasis on developing detailed dynamic general equilibrium models. Within environmental economics, he models the effects of alternative environmental policies such as carbon taxes, cap-and-trade programs, and clean energy standards in economies with multiple non-environmental frictions and distortions on key outcomes such as emissions reductions, welfare, and employment. Within the field of macroeconomics, his interests are focused on measuring the impact of micro-frictions on aggregate outcomes and the implications of those frictions on macroeconomic and monetary policy.

Views expressed above are those of the author. Resources for the Future does not take institutional positions on legislative or policy questions. All information contained on Common Resources is intended for informational and educational purposes and may only be used for these purposes. Please see RFF's Terms of Use for further information.

Leave A Comment